Skip to main content

Time-delayed local feedback control for a chaotic finance system

Abstract

In this paper, we consider the local control problem for a chaotic finance system via the time-delayed feedback. Using the Lyapunov–Krasovskii stability theorem, the quadratic system theory, some integral inequalities, and rigorous mathematical analysis, we obtain a local stabilization condition by means of linear matrix inequalities. Then we discuss the estimate of the region of asymptotic stability and give the corresponding optimization problem. Also, we address the local control problem under the nondelayed feedback. Finally, we present numerical simulations to show the effectiveness of the proposed results.

1 Introduction

In the past several decades, the dynamical behaviors have attracted significant research attention for various kinds of nonlinear finance systems [16]. It has been widely identified that the chaotic behavior is encountered in financial/economic systems. Moreover, it has been well acknowledged that the existence of the chaotic phenomenon in financial/economic systems will lead to a possible uncertainty in the macroeconomic operation. Hence it is important to investigate stabilization and synchronization problems for various kinds of chaotic finance systems [712]. For example, the stabilization problem has been studied in [9] for an uncertain fractional-order finance system via the adaptive sliding-mode strategy, and in [11] the stabilization and synchronization problems have been addressed for an uncertain financial hyperchaotic system by using the impulsive control approach. In [12] the adaptive control scheme has been used to control a novel finance system.

In [13, 14] the time-delayed feedback control (TDFC) has been recognized as an effective method for controlling chaos in nonlinear dynamical systems. Compared with some other control schemes, the TDFC is more convenient to be implemented in practice since it does not require the reference signal that corresponds to the unstable periodic orbit. Over the past more than a decade, the TDFC has been extensively utilized to control the nonlinear finance systems [1519]. For example, the minimum entropy algorithm has been applied in [16] for controlling chaos in the Behrens–Feichtinger model through TDFC, and in [18] the dynamical behavior has been studied for a nonlinear finance system under TDFC by using the characteristic equation of the linearized model. In [19] the \(H_{\infty }\) control problem has been addressed for a finance system with external disturbance via TDFC.

Nevertheless, it should be pointed out that the results in [16, 17] are mainly based on the numerical simulations, and the discussions in [15, 18] are based on the characteristic equations of the corresponding linearized models. It is obvious that the theoretical analysis in [16, 17] is absent, and the application ranges of the results in [15, 18] are unknown. In addition, it is worth mentioning that all unstable equilibrium points in [19] are controlled by a unified delayed feedback controller, and this makes the resultant design condition a bit rigorous.

The finance systems discussed in the existing literature are essentially nonlinear quadratic systems. The stability analysis and control design for quadratic systems have also received wide investigations in the past more than a decade [2025]. In particular, in [2325] the time delay is incorporated in the considered models. However, note that the results in [2325] are concerned with models with a single state delay and cannot be applied to the finance system subject to TDFC. Moreover, the analysis approaches used in [2325] are somewhat conservative.

Motivated by these discussions, this paper is concerned with the TDFC problem for a chaotic finance system by using the quadratic system theory. By incorporating an augmented Lyapunov–Krasovskii (L–K) functional, some integral inequalities, and rigorous mathematical analysis the local control design conditions are first obtained in the context of linear matrix inequalities (LMIs). Then the paper discusses the estimate of the stability region and proposes the corresponding optimization problems. Finally, numerical simulations demonstrate the effectiveness of the obtained results. The main contributions of this paper are as follows: (1) a new local stabilization condition is established for a typical finance system under the TDFC strategy, and (2) the estimate of the region of asymptotic stability is discussed for the first time, and the corresponding optimization problem is formulated.

Notation. The superscript ``T” is the transpose of a matrix. For a matrix P, \(P>0\)\((P\geq 0)\) means that P is symmetric and positive definite (positive semidefinite). By \(\|\cdot \|\) we denote the 2-norm of a vector and by \(\lambda (\cdot )_{M}\) the maximum eigenvalue value of a matrix. The symmetric terms in a matrix are denoted by .

2 Problem formulation

In [1, 2] the finance model composed of four subblocks (i.e., production, money, stock, and labor force) has been purified and simplified as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \textstyle\begin{cases} \dot{\mathbf{x}}(t)=f_{1}(\mathbf{y}(t)-{\mathrm{SV}})\mathbf{x}(t)+f_{2} \mathbf{z}(t), \\ \dot{\mathbf{y}}(t)=f_{3}({\mathrm{BEN}}-\alpha \mathbf{y}(t)-\beta \mathbf{x}^{2}(t)), \\ \dot{\mathbf{z}}(t)=-f_{4}\mathbf{z}(t)-f_{5}\mathbf{x}(t), \end{cases}\displaystyle \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(\mathbf{x}(t)\), \(\mathbf{y}(t)\), \(\mathbf{z}(t)\), SV, and BEN denote, respectively, the interest rate, the investment demand, the price index, the amount of savings, and the benefit rate of investment; α, β, and \(f_{i}\) (\(i=1,2,\ldots,5\)) are all constants. Model (1) is obtained through careful analysis and many experiments. We see that nine independent parameters are involved in the model. By choosing an appropriate coordinate system and setting an appropriate dimension to every state variable, model (1) has been further simplified for convenience of analysis [1, 2]. The further simplified model contains only three most important parameters and is described as

$$\begin{aligned} \textstyle\begin{cases} \dot{x}_{1}(t)=x_{3}(t)+(x_{2}(t)-a)x_{1}(t), \\ \dot{x}_{2}(t)=1-bx_{2}(t)-x_{1}^{2}(t), \\ \dot{x}_{3}(t)=-x_{1}(t)-cx_{3}(t), \end{cases}\displaystyle \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where a, b, and c are some positive scalars representing, respectively, the saving amount, the cost per investment, and the demand elasticity of commercial markets.

Denote \(\Delta \triangleq c-b-abc\). It is easy to see that if \(\Delta <0\), then model (2) has a unique fixed point \((0,1/b,0)\), and if \(\Delta >0\), then model (2) has three fixed points

$$\begin{aligned} (0,1/b,0), \quad\bigl(\pm \sqrt{\Delta /c},(ac+1)/c,\mp \sqrt{\Delta /c^{3}}\bigr). \end{aligned}$$

For the finance model (2), it has been verified that the dynamic behaviors are highly correlated with parameters a, b, and c. In many cases the fixed points of system (2) are unstable. For example, when we choose \(a=3\), \(b=0.1\), and \(c=1\) or \(a=2.5\), \(b=0.2\), and \(c=1.2\), a chaotic behavior occurs in system (2).

Letting \(x(t)\triangleq [x_{1}(t) x_{2}(t) x_{3}(t)]^{T}\) and

$$\begin{aligned} A\triangleq \begin{bmatrix} -a&0&1 \\ 0&-b&0 \\ -1&0&-c \end{bmatrix},\qquad f\bigl(x(t)\bigr)\triangleq \begin{bmatrix} x_{1}(t)x_{2}(t) \\ 1-x_{1}^{2}(t) \\ 0 \end{bmatrix}, \end{aligned}$$

the chaotic finance system (2) can be read as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{x}(t)=Ax(t)+f\bigl(x(t)\bigr)+u(t). \end{aligned}$$
(3)

In this paper, we apply the TDFC scheme

$$\begin{aligned} u(t)=K\bigl(x(t)-x(t-\tau )\bigr), \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where K is the controller gain matrix.

Denoting a fixed point by \(x^{\ast }\), we see that

$$\begin{aligned} Ax^{*}+f\bigl(x^{*}\bigr)=0. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Denoting \(e(t)\triangleq x(t)-x^{*}\) and using (3)–(5), we have the closed-loop dynamics

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{e}(t)=&(A+K)e(t)-Ke(t-\tau )+f\bigl(x(t)\bigr)-f\bigl(x^{*} \bigr). \end{aligned}$$
(6)

Note that \(f(x(t))-f(x^{*})=Fe(t)+g(e(t))\), where

$$\begin{aligned} F=& \begin{bmatrix} x_{2}^{*}&x_{1}^{*}&0 \\ -2x_{1}^{*}&0&0 \\ 0&0&0 \end{bmatrix},\qquad g(e)= \begin{bmatrix} e_{1}e_{2} \\ -e_{1}^{2} \\ 0 \end{bmatrix}= \begin{bmatrix} e^{T}B_{1} \\ e^{T}B_{2} \\ e^{T}B_{3} \end{bmatrix}e \triangleq B(e)e \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} &B_{1}= \begin{bmatrix} 0&1/2&0 \\ 1/2&0&0 \\ 0&0&0 \end{bmatrix},\qquad B_{2}= \begin{bmatrix} -1&0&0 \\ 0&0&0 \\ 0&0&0 \end{bmatrix},\qquad B_{3}=0_{3\times 3}. \end{aligned}$$

Then we obtain the following closed-loop dynamics:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{e}(t)=&\bigl[A+F+K+B(e)\bigr]e(t)-Ke(t-\tau ). \end{aligned}$$
(7)

The initial condition associated with system (7) is denoted by \(e(s)=\phi (s)\), \(s\in [-\tau,0)\). Moreover, it is reasonable to assume that the initial condition \(\phi (s)\) (\(s\in [-\tau,0)\)) satisfies the open-loop dynamics \(\dot{\phi }(s)=[A+F+B(\phi )]\phi (s)\).

In this paper, we assume that the initial condition \(\phi (s)\) (\(s \in [-\tau,0)\)) of the closed-loop dynamics (7) belongs to a set of the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} X_{\rho }= \bigl\{ \phi (s)\in C^{1}[-\tau,0]: \mathop{\operatorname{max}}_{s\in [- \tau,0]} \bigl\Vert \phi (s) \bigr\Vert \leq \rho \bigr\} , \end{aligned}$$
(8)

where \(\rho >0\) is a scalar to be maximized.

For system (2), it is almost impossible to design the controller (4) such that the closed-loop dynamics (7) is globally asymptotically stable. The main aim of this paper designing the time-delayed feedback controller (4) such that the closed-loop error dynamics (7) is locally asymptotically stable. Meanwhile, we would like to obtain an estimate (of the form \(X_{\rho }\)) of the asymptotic stability region.

For the local analysis of dynamics (7), we introduce the box

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{X}=[-\bar{e}_{1},\bar{e}_{1}]\times [- \bar{e}_{2},\bar{e}_{2}] \times [-\bar{e}_{3}, \bar{e}_{3}], \end{aligned}$$
(9)

which can be equivalently written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{X}=\operatorname{Co}\{v_{1},v_{2}, \ldots,v_{8}\} = \bigl\{ e\in \mathbb{R}^{3}: \vert h_{i}e \vert \leq \bar{e}_{i},i=1,2,3 \bigr\} , \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where “Co” is the convex hull, and \(v_{i}\), \(h_{j}\)\((i=1,2,\ldots,8,j=1,2,3)\) are given as

v1=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,v2=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,v3=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,v4=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,v5=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,v6=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,v7=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,v8=[e¯1e¯2e¯3]T,h1=[100],h2=[010],h3=[001].

Next, we introduce several indispensable integral inequalities.

Lemma 1

([26, 27])

For a given\(n\times n\)matrix\(Z>0\), two scalarsaandbsatisfying\(b>a\)and a differentiable vector function\(\omega (t) \in \mathbb{R}^{n}\), we have the following integral inequalities:

$$\begin{aligned} &(1) \quad (b-a) \int ^{b}_{a}\omega ^{T}(s)Z\rho (s) \, \mathrm{d}s \\ &\phantom{(1) \quad}\quad\geq \biggl( \int ^{b}_{a}\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s \biggr)^{T} Z \biggl( \int ^{b}_{a}\rho (s) \,\mathrm{d}s \biggr)+3 \varOmega _{1}^{T}Z\varOmega _{1}, \\ &(2) \quad (b-a) \int ^{b}_{a}\omega ^{T}(s)Z\omega (s) \, \mathrm{d}s\geq \biggl( \int ^{b}_{a}\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s \biggr)^{T} \\ &\phantom{(2) \quad}\qquad{}\times Z \biggl( \int ^{b}_{a}\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s \biggr)+3 \varOmega _{1}^{T}Z \varOmega _{1}+5\varOmega _{2}^{T}Z\varOmega _{2}, \\ & (3)\quad \frac{(b-a)^{2}}{2} \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{\theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d} \theta \geq \biggl( \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{ \theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d} \theta \biggr)^{T} \\ &\phantom{(1) \quad}\qquad{}\times Z \biggl( \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{\theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s \,\mathrm{d} \theta \biggr)+8\varOmega _{3}^{T}Z\varOmega _{3}, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \varOmega _{1}={}& \int ^{b}_{a}\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s- \frac{2}{b-a} \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{\theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d} \theta, \\ \varOmega _{2}={}& \int ^{b}_{a}\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s- \frac{6}{b-a} \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{\theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d} \theta \\ &{}+\frac{12}{(b-a)^{2}} \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{\lambda } \int ^{b}_{ \theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d} \theta \,\mathrm{d}\lambda, \\ \varOmega _{3}={}& \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{\theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s \,\mathrm{d} \theta -\frac{3}{b-a} \int ^{b}_{a} \int ^{b}_{\lambda } \int ^{b}_{ \theta }\omega (s) \,\mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d} \theta \,\mathrm{d}\lambda. \end{aligned}$$

3 Main results

In this section, we first consider the local stabilization problem by using the L–K stability theory and the quadratic system theory in the context of LMIs.

For presentation convenience, we denote

$$\begin{aligned} &\vartheta _{1}(t)\triangleq \int ^{t}_{t-\tau }e(s)\,\mathrm{d}s, \qquad\vartheta _{2}(t)\triangleq \int ^{0}_{-\tau } \int ^{t}_{t+\theta }e(s) \,\mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d}\theta, \\ &\mathcal{E}(R,1)\triangleq \bigl\{ e\in \mathbb{R}^{3}: e^{T}\operatorname{Re}\leq 1, R>0 \bigr\} ,\qquad \mathcal{D}(\kappa ) \triangleq \bigl\{ e\in \mathbb{R}^{3}: \Vert e \Vert ^{2} \leq \kappa ^{2} \bigr\} . \end{aligned}$$

Theorem 1

Let\(\bar{e}_{1}>0\), \(\bar{e}_{2}>0\), \(\bar{e}_{3}>0\), \(\delta >0\), and\(\tau >0\)be given scalars. The closed-loop dynamics (7) is locally asymptotically stable if there exist\(9\times 9\)-dimensional symmetric matrix\(P=(P_{ij})_{3\times 3}\)and\(3\times 3\)-dimensional matrices\(Q>0\), \(Z>0\), \(R>0\), X, andYsuch that the following LMIs hold:

$$\begin{aligned} & \begin{bmatrix} \varPhi _{11}^{v_{i}}&\varPhi _{12}&\varPhi _{13}&\varPhi _{14}&\varPhi _{15}^{v_{i}} \\ *&\varPhi _{22}&\varPhi _{23}&\varPhi _{24}&-\delta Y^{T} \\ *&*&\varPhi _{33}&\varPhi _{34}&P_{12}^{T} \\ *&*&*&\varPhi _{44}&P_{13}^{T} \\ *&*&*&*&\varPhi _{55} \end{bmatrix}< 0,\quad i=1,2,\ldots,8, \end{aligned}$$
(11)
$$\begin{aligned} &P+ \begin{bmatrix} \varPi _{11}&6Z&-24Z/\tau \\ *&\varPi _{22}&\varPi _{23} \\ *&*&\varPi _{33} \end{bmatrix}\geq 0, \end{aligned}$$
(12)
$$\begin{aligned} &h_{1}^{T}h_{1}\leq \bar{e}_{1}^{2}R,\qquad h_{2}^{T}h_{2}\leq \bar{e}_{2}^{2}R,\qquad h_{3}^{T}h_{3} \leq \bar{e}_{3}^{2}R, \end{aligned}$$
(13)

where\(P_{ij}\), \(1\leq i\leq j\leq 3\), are\(3\times 3\)-dimensional, and

$$\begin{aligned} \varPhi _{11}^{v_{i}}={}&X\bigl[A+F+B(v_{i})\bigr]+ \bigl[A+F+B(v_{i})\bigr]^{T}X^{T}+Y \\ &{}+Y^{T}+P_{12}+P_{12}^{T}+\tau \bigl(P_{13}+P_{13}^{T}\bigr)+Q-9Z, \\ \varPhi _{12}={}&3Z-Y-P_{12}, \qquad \varPhi _{13}=P_{22}-P_{13}+ \tau P_{23}^{T}-24Z/ \tau, \\ \varPhi _{14}={}&P_{23}+\tau P_{33}+60Z/\bigl(\tau ^{2}\bigr),\qquad \varPhi _{22}=-Q-9Z, \\ \varPhi _{15}^{v_{i}}={}&-X+\delta \bigl[A+F+B(v_{i} \bigr]^{T}X^{T}+\delta Y^{T}+P_{11}, \\ \varPhi _{23}={}&-P_{22}+36Z/\tau,\qquad \varPhi _{24}=-P_{23}-60Z/\bigl(\tau ^{2}\bigr), \\ \varPhi _{33}={}&-P_{23}-P_{23}^{T}-192Z/ \bigl(\tau ^{2}\bigr), \qquad \varPhi _{44}=-720Z/\bigl( \tau ^{4}\bigr), \\ \varPhi _{34}={}&-P_{33}+360Z/\bigl(\tau ^{3}\bigr),\qquad \varPhi _{55}=\tau ^{2}Z-\delta (X+X)^{T}, \\ \varPi _{11}={}&{-}R+6\tau Z,\qquad \varPi _{22}=(4Q+18Z)/\tau, \\ \varPi _{23}={}&{-}6(Q+8Z)/\bigl(\tau ^{2}\bigr),\qquad \varPi _{33}=12(Q+12Z)/\bigl(\tau ^{3}\bigr). \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, if there exists feasible solutions, then the controller gain is given by the matrix\(K=X^{-1}Y\).

Proof

Choose the following augmented L–K functional:

$$\begin{aligned} V(t)=&\eta ^{T}(t)P\eta (t)+ \int ^{t}_{t-\tau }e^{T}(s)Qe(s) \,\mathrm{d}s +\tau \int ^{0}_{-\tau } \int ^{t}_{t+\theta }\dot{e}^{T}(s)Z \dot{e}(s)\, \mathrm{d}s\,\mathrm{d}\theta, \end{aligned}$$
(14)

where η(t)=[eT(t)ϑ1T(t)ϑ2T(t)]T.

Through some direct calculations, we can obtain that

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{V}(t)={}&2\eta ^{T}(t)P\dot{\eta }(t)+e^{T}(t)Qe(t)-e^{T}(t- \tau )Qe(t- \tau ) \\ &{}+\tau ^{2}\dot{e}^{T}(t)Z\dot{e}(t)-\tau \int ^{t}_{t-\tau }\dot{e}^{T}(s)Z \dot{e}(s)\, \mathrm{d}s. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Using the second inequality in Lemma 1, we see that

$$\begin{aligned} &-\tau \int ^{t}_{t-\tau }\dot{e}^{T}(s)Z\dot{e}(s)\, \mathrm{d}s \leq - \begin{bmatrix} \xi _{1}(t) \\ \xi _{2}(t) \\ \xi _{3}(t) \end{bmatrix}^{T} \begin{bmatrix} Z&0&0 \\ 0&3Z&0 \\ 0&0&5Z \end{bmatrix} \begin{bmatrix} \xi _{1}(t) \\ \xi _{2}(t) \\ \xi _{3}(t) \end{bmatrix}, \end{aligned}$$
(16)

where

$$\begin{aligned} &\xi _{1}(t)=e(t)-e(t-\tau ),\qquad \xi _{2}(t)=e(t)+e(t-\tau )-(2/\tau ) \vartheta _{1}(t), \\ &\xi _{3}(t)=e(t)-e(t-\tau )+(6/\tau )\vartheta _{1}(t)- \bigl(12/\tau ^{2}\bigr) \vartheta _{2}(t). \end{aligned}$$

Denoting \(\tilde{A}(e)\triangleq A+F+K+B(e)\), from (7) it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} 2\bigl[e^{T}(t)+\delta \dot{e}^{T}(t)\bigr]X\bigl[ \tilde{A}(e)e(t)-Ke(t-\tau )- \dot{e}(t)\bigr]=0. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

Adding the left side of (17) to \(\dot{V}(t)\) and using (16) yield that

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{V}(t)\leq \zeta ^{T}(t)\varPhi (e)\zeta (t), \end{aligned}$$
(18)

where ζ(t)=[eT(t)eT(tτ)ϑ1T(t)ϑ2T(t)e˙T(t)]T, and

$$\begin{aligned} \varPhi (e)= \begin{bmatrix} \varPhi _{11}(e)&\tilde{\varPhi }_{12}&\varPhi _{13}&\varPhi _{14}&\varPhi _{15}(e) \\ *&\varPhi _{22}&\varPhi _{23}&\varPhi _{24}&-\delta K^{T}X^{T} \\ *&*&\varPhi _{33}&\varPhi _{34}&P_{12}^{T} \\ *&*&*&\varPhi _{44}&P_{13}^{T} \\ *&*&*&*&\varPhi _{55} \end{bmatrix} \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} \varPhi _{11}(e)={}&X\bigl[A+F+B(e)+K\bigr]+\bigl[A+F+B(e)+K \bigr]^{T}X^{T}+P_{12} \\ &{} +P_{12}^{T}+\tau \bigl(P_{13}+P_{13}^{T} \bigr)+Q-9Z, \tilde{\varPhi }_{12}=3Z-K^{T}X^{T}-P_{12}, \\ \varPhi _{15}(e)={}&{-}X+\delta \bigl[A+F+B(e)+K\bigr]^{T}X^{T}+P_{11}. \end{aligned}$$

Let \(Y\triangleq XK\) and note that \(\varPhi (e)\) is affine with respect to \(e_{1}\), \(e_{2}\), and \(e_{3}\). Hence, if LMIs (11) were true, then the inequality \(\varPhi (e)<0\) could be ensured on \(\mathcal{X}\). Then we have

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{V}(t)< 0 \end{aligned}$$
(19)

on the box \(\mathcal{X}\), which implies that

$$\begin{aligned} V(t)\leq V(0), \quad t\geq 0. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

On the other hand, using the inequalities (1) and (3) in Lemma 1, we have [28, 29]

$$\begin{aligned} V(t)\geq {}&\eta ^{T}(t)P\eta (t)+(1/\tau )\vartheta _{1}^{T}(t)Q \vartheta _{1}(t)+(3/\tau )\bigl[ \vartheta _{1}(t)-(2/\tau )\vartheta _{2}(t) \bigr]^{T} \\ &{}\times Q\bigl[\vartheta _{1}(t)-(2/\tau )\vartheta _{2}(t) \bigr]+(2/\tau )\bigl[ \tau e(t)-\vartheta _{1}(t)\bigr]^{T} \\ &{}\times Z\bigl[\tau e(t)-\vartheta _{1}(t)\bigr]+(4/\tau )\bigl[\tau e(t)+2 \vartheta _{1}(t)-(6/\tau )\vartheta _{2}(t) \bigr]^{T} \\ &{}\times Z\bigl[\tau e(t)+2\vartheta _{1}(t)-(6/\tau )\vartheta _{2}(t)\bigr]= \eta ^{T}(t) (P+\varPi )\eta (t), \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where

$$\begin{aligned} &\varPi = \begin{bmatrix} 6\tau Z&6Z&-24Z/\tau \\ *&\varPi _{22}&\varPi _{23} \\ *&*&\varPi _{33} \end{bmatrix}. \end{aligned}$$

By (12) and (21) it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} V(t)\geq e^{T}(t)\operatorname{Re}(t), \end{aligned}$$
(22)

which shows that the L–K functional \(V(t)\) is positive definite.

In addition, from (13) we can infer that

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{E}(R,1)\subseteq \mathcal{X}. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

For all initial conditions \(\phi (s)\in X_{\rho }\) satisfying \(V(0)\leq 1\), we can see from (20) and (22) that all trajectories \(e(t)\) are contained in the set \(\mathcal{E}(R,1)\). By (19) and (23) we conclude that the closed-loop dynamics (7) is asymptotically stable for all \(\phi (s)\) satisfying \(V(0)\leq 1\) [20, 24], and this completes the proof. □

Remark 1

The finance model (2) is essentially a particular kind of quadratic system [2025]. However, it is worth pointing out that the existing results concerning quadratic systems cannot be directly applied to the finance system (2) subject to TDFC. Moreover, differently from the results in [2325], the augmented L–K functional and the advanced integral inequalities are utilized in this paper. In addition, it is worth mentioning that the matrix P in Theorem 1 is not required to be positive definite.

Remark 2

Model (2) considered in this paper is simple yet typical. In fact, several recent finance models are derived from model (2), such as the hyperchaotic finance system [5], the delayed finance system [6], and fractional-order economic system [7]. The proposed results in this paper can be readily extended to the finance systems discussed in [5, 6] and model (1) in this paper.

If we employ the nondelayed feedback

$$\begin{aligned} u(t)=K\bigl(x(t)-x^{*}\bigr), \end{aligned}$$
(24)

then the closed-loop dynamics (7) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{e}(t)=\bigl[A+F+K+B(e)\bigr]e(t). \end{aligned}$$
(25)

Correspondingly, we easily obtain the following condition.

Corollary 1

Let\(\bar{e}_{1}>0\), \(\bar{e}_{2}>0\), \(\bar{e}_{3}>0\), and\(\delta >0\)be given scalars. The chaotic finance system (2) can be locally asymptotically stabilized by the feedback controller (24) with\(K=X^{-1}Y\)if there exist\(3\times 3\)-dimensional matrices\(P>0\), X, andYsuch that the following LMIs hold:

$$\begin{aligned} & \begin{bmatrix} \varPsi _{1}^{v_{i}}&\varPsi _{2}^{v_{i}} \\ *&-\delta (X+X)^{T} \end{bmatrix}< 0, \quad i=1,2,\ldots,8, \end{aligned}$$
(26)
$$\begin{aligned} &h_{1}^{T}h_{1}\leq \bar{e}_{1}^{2}P,\qquad h_{2}^{T}h_{2}\leq \bar{e}_{2}^{2}P,\qquad h_{3}^{T}h_{3} \leq \bar{e}_{3}^{2}P, \end{aligned}$$
(27)

where

$$\begin{aligned} &\varPsi _{1}^{v_{i}}=X\bigl[A+F+B(v_{i})\bigr]+ \bigl[A+F+B(v_{i})\bigr]^{T}X^{T}+Y+Y^{T}, \\ &\varPsi _{2}^{v_{i}}=-X+\delta \bigl[A+F+B(v_{i} \bigr]^{T}X^{T}+\delta Y^{T}+P. \end{aligned}$$

We further consider the estimate of the asymptotic stability region involved in Theorem 1 and Corollary 1. To this end, we introduce the inequalities

$$\begin{aligned} \textstyle\begin{cases} P\leq \operatorname{diag}\{P_{1},P_{2},P_{3}\},\quad P_{1}\leq p_{1}I, \\ P_{2}\leq p_{2}I,\qquad P_{3}\leq p_{3}I,\qquad Q\leq qI, \qquad Z\leq zI, \end{cases}\displaystyle \end{aligned}$$
(28)

where \(P_{i}>0\), \(p_{i}>0\)\((i=1,2,3)\), \(q>0\), and \(z>0\).

Using (28) and the Jensen integral inequalities [30], it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} V(0)\leq {}&\lambda _{1}\mathop{\operatorname{max}}_{s\in [-\tau,0]} \bigl\Vert \phi (s) \bigr\Vert ^{2}+ \lambda _{2}{\operatorname{max}}_{s\in [-\tau,0]} \bigl\Vert \dot{\phi }(s) \bigr\Vert ^{2} \\ \leq {}&\tilde{\lambda }_{1}\mathop{\operatorname{max}}_{s\in [-\tau,0]} \bigl\Vert \phi (s) \bigr\Vert ^{2}+\tilde{\lambda }_{2} \mathop{\operatorname{max}}_{s\in [-\tau,0]} \bigl\Vert \dot{\phi }(s) \bigr\Vert ^{2}, \end{aligned}$$
(29)

where

$$\begin{aligned} &\lambda _{1}=\bigl[\lambda _{M}(P_{1})+\tau ^{2}\lambda _{M}(P_{2})+\bigl( \tau ^{4}/4\bigr)\lambda _{M}(P_{3})+\tau \lambda _{M}(Q)\bigr], \\ &\lambda _{2}=\bigl(\tau ^{3}/2\bigr)\lambda _{M}(Z), \qquad\tilde{\lambda }_{1}=p_{1}+ \tau ^{2}p_{2}+\bigl(\tau ^{4}/4\bigr)p_{3}+ \tau q, \qquad \tilde{\lambda }_{2}=\bigl(\tau ^{3}/2\bigr)z. \end{aligned}$$

Then the maximization of the estimate of the asymptotic stability region in Theorem 1 can be formulated as follows.

Problem 1

\(\min _{P,P_{1},P_{2},P_{3},Q,Z,X,Y,p_{1},p_{2},p_{3},q,z} ( \tilde{\lambda }_{1}+\tilde{\lambda }_{2})\) s.t. LMIs (11)–(13) and (28). hold.

By solving Problem 1 we can obtain the scalars \(\lambda _{1}\) and \(\lambda _{2}\). Recalling that the initial condition \(\phi (s)\) satisfies \(V(0)\leq 1\), by (29) we can require \(\phi (s)\) to satisfy

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{1}\mathop{\operatorname{max}}_{s\in [-\tau,0]} \bigl\Vert \phi (s) \bigr\Vert ^{2}+ \lambda _{2}\mathop{\operatorname{max}}_{s\in [-\tau,0]} \bigl\Vert \dot{\phi }(s) \bigr\Vert ^{2} \leq 1. \end{aligned}$$
(30)

From (30) we see that \(\|\phi (s)\|_{c}^{2}\leq 1/\rho _{1}\), which shows that all admissible \(\phi (s)\) are contained in the ball \(\mathcal{D}(\sqrt{1/\lambda _{1}})\). Let us choose a box \(\tilde{\mathcal{X}}=[-\omega,\omega ]\times [-\omega,\omega ] \times [-\omega,\omega ]\) such that the ball \(\mathcal{D}(\sqrt{1/\lambda _{1}})\) is contained in \(\tilde{\mathcal{X}}\), that is, \(\mathcal{D}(\sqrt{1/\lambda _{1}})\subseteq \tilde{\mathcal{X}}\). Recalling that \(\dot{\phi }(s)=[A+F+B(\phi )]\phi (s)\), we see that the matrix inequality

$$\begin{aligned} \bigl[A+F+B(\phi )\bigr]^{T}\bigl[A+F+B(\phi )\bigr]\leq \gamma I \end{aligned}$$
(31)

can ensure that \(\dot{\phi }^{T}(s)\dot{\phi }(s)\leq \gamma \phi ^{T}(s)\phi (s)\). Noting that \(\phi \in \mathcal{D}(\sqrt{1/\lambda _{1}})\), it follows that the matrix inequality (31) can be ensured by the LMIs

$$\begin{aligned} & \begin{bmatrix} \gamma I&[A+F+B(\tilde{v}_{i})]^{T} \\ *&I \end{bmatrix}\geq 0,\quad i=1,2, \ldots,8, \end{aligned}$$
(32)

where \(\tilde{v}_{i}\)\((i=1,2,\ldots,8)\) are the vertices of the box \(\tilde{\mathcal{X}}\).

By solving LMIs (32) can readily obtain the minimum γ. Furthermore, from (29) and (31) we see that the maximum admissible bound of the initial condition set \(X_{\rho }\) involved in Theorem 1 can be given by \(\rho =1/\sqrt{(\lambda _{1}+\gamma \lambda _{2})}\).

In Corollary 1 the ellipsoid \(\mathcal{E}(P,1)\) can be seen as an estimate of the asymptotic stability region. The corresponding optimization problem can be written as

Problem 2

\(\min_{P,X,Y,p} p\) s.t. LMIs (26)–(27) and \(P\leq pI\) hold.

Remark 3

In the past more than a decade the TDFC strategy has been widely applied for controlling chaos in nonlinear finance systems [1519]. Unlike most existing results, our obtained results are based on the rigorous mathematical theories such as the L–K theorem and the quadratic systems theory. Moreover, the results in this paper are based on the finance system itself, not on its linearized mode. In addition, it is worth mentioning that the estimate \(X_{\rho }\) and its maximization of the asymptotic stability region have been discussed in this paper. It is obvious that our proposed results are indispensable supplements of the existing ones.

Remark 4

The obtained results in this paper are expressed by means of LMIs, which can be conveniently solved by Matlab LMI Control Toolbox.

4 Numerical simulations

In this section, we illustrate the effectiveness of our proposed results via numerical simulations. Choosing \(a=2.5\), \(b=0.2\), and \(c=1.2\), we easily verify that system (2) has three unstable fixed points

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb{P}_{1}^{*}\triangleq (\nu _{1},\nu _{2},-\nu _{3}), \qquad \mathbb{P}_{2}^{*} \triangleq (-\nu _{1},\nu _{2},\nu _{3}),\qquad \mathbb{P}_{3}^{*}\triangleq (0,5,0), \end{aligned}$$

where \(\nu _{1}=0.5774\), \(\nu _{2}=3.3333\), and \(\nu _{3}=0.4811\).

First, we address the local stabilization problem via the time-delayed feedback controller (4). For the fixed point \(\mathbb{P}_{1}^{*}\), by solving the Problem 1 with \(\tau =0.5\), \(\bar{e}_{1}=0.46\), \(\bar{e}_{2}=0.46\), \(\bar{e}_{3}=1\), and \(\delta =0.33\), we obtain \(\lambda _{1}=19.0787\) and \(\lambda _{2}=0.3153\) and the following controller gain:

$$\begin{aligned} K= \begin{bmatrix} -1.6647&2.0298&0.7061 \\ -1.2980&-3.2695&0.1205 \\ 0.5648&-0.1501&-0.1977 \end{bmatrix} \bigl(\mathbb{P}_{1}^{*} \bigr). \end{aligned}$$

Choosing \(\omega =0.2290\) such that \(\mathcal{D}(\sqrt{1/\lambda _{1}})\subseteq \tilde{\mathcal{X}}\) and applying LMIs (32), we get the minimum \(\gamma =5.6445\). Then we obtain the bound \(\rho =0.2190\) of the initial condition set \(X_{\rho }\). Similarly, for the fixed point \(\mathbb{P}_{2}^{*}\), we have \(\rho =0.2190\) and

$$\begin{aligned} K= \begin{bmatrix} -1.6646&-2.0300&0.7064 \\ 1.2980&-3.2693&-0.1204 \\ 0.5646&0.1504&-0.1981 \end{bmatrix} \bigl(\mathbb{P}_{2}^{*} \bigr). \end{aligned}$$

Next, we consider the local stabilization problem via the nondelayed feedback controller (24). Choosing \(\bar{e}_{1}=\bar{e}_{2}=5\), \(\bar{e}_{3}=10\), and \(\delta =1\) and then solving Problem 2, we obtain the ellipsoid \(\mathcal{E}(P,1)\) and the corresponding controller gains with

$$\begin{aligned} &P= \begin{bmatrix} 0.0400&0.0000&-0.0000 \\ 0.0000&0.0400&-0.0000 \\ -0.0000&-0.0000&0.0370 \end{bmatrix} \bigl(\mathbb{P}_{1}^{*}, \mathbb{P}_{2}^{*}, \mathbb{P}_{3}^{*} \bigr), \\ &K= \begin{bmatrix} -9.9927&-0.5774&-1.0000 \\ 1.1548&-17.2375&-0.0000 \\ 1.0000&-0.0000&0.2000 \end{bmatrix} \bigl(\mathbb{P}_{1}^{*} \bigr), \\ &K= \begin{bmatrix} -10.0146&0.5774&-1.0000 \\ -1.1548&-17.1628&-0.0000 \\ 1.0000&0.0000&0.2000 \end{bmatrix} \bigl(\mathbb{P}_{2}^{*} \bigr), \\ &K= \begin{bmatrix} -11.6791&0.0000&-1.0000 \\ -0.0000&-17.1725&0.0000 \\ 1.0000&0.0000&0.2000 \end{bmatrix} \bigl(\mathbb{P}_{3}^{*} \bigr). \end{aligned}$$

Using the obtained controller gains, we plotted the state responses of the closed-loop dynamics in Figs. 15, from which it is clear that our proposed control strategy is really effective in controlling the chaotic finance system (2).

Figure 1
figure 1

State responses of the closed-loop dynamics (7) (\(\mathbb{P}_{1}^{*}\))

Figure 2
figure 2

State responses of the closed-loop dynamics (7) (\(\mathbb{P}_{2}^{*}\))

Figure 3
figure 3

State responses of the closed-loop dynamics (25) (\(\mathbb{P}_{1}^{*}\))

Figure 4
figure 4

State responses of the closed-loop dynamics (25) (\(\mathbb{P}_{2}^{*}\))

Figure 5
figure 5

State responses of the closed-loop dynamics (25) (\(\mathbb{P}_{3}^{*}\))

5 Conclusions

In this paper, we have considered the local control problem for a chaotic finance system via TDFC scheme. By using an augmented L–K functional, the quadratic system theory, and rigorous mathematical analysis, we have established the local stabilization conditions in terms of LMIs. Subsequently, we discussed the estimate and its maximization of the asymptotic stability region. Finally, by simulation results we demonstrated the effectiveness of the obtained conditions. The techniques developed in this paper can be employed to investigate the synchronization problem [8, 11, 31] and the \(H_{\infty }\) control problem [19, 32, 33]. In addition, it is worth pointing out that there exists conservatism in our results. By utilizing the recently developed integral inequalities [34] and L–K functionals [35, 36] we can establish less conservative results, which is our further work.

References

  1. Huang, D.-S., Li, H.-Q.: Theory and Method of the Nonlinear Economics Publishing. House of Sichuan University, Chengdu (1993) (in Chinese)

    Google Scholar 

  2. Ma, J.-H., Chen, Y.-S.: Study for the bifurcation topological structure and the global complicated character of a kind of nonlinear finance system (I). Appl. Math. Mech. 22(11), 1240–1251 (2001)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Ma, J.-H., Chen, Y.-S.: Study for the bifurcation topological structure and the global complicated character of a kind of nonlinear finance system (II). Appl. Math. Mech. 22(12), 1375–1382 (2001)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Cesare, L.D., Sportelli, M.: A dynamic IS-LM model with delayed taxation revenues. Chaos Solitons Fractals 25(1), 233–244 (2005)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Yu, H., Cai, G., Li, Y.: Dynamic analysis and control of a new hyperchaotic finance system. Nonlinear Dyn. 67(3), 2171–2182 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Chen, X., Liu, H., Xu, C.: The new result on delayed finance system. Nonlinear Dyn. 78(3), 1989–1998 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Dadras, S., Momeni, H.R.: Control of a fractional-order economical system via sliding mode. Physica A 389(12), 2434–2442 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Zhao, X., Li, Z., Li, S.: Synchronization of a chaotic finance system. Appl. Math. Comput. 217(13), 6031–6039 (2011)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Wang, Z., Huang, X., Shen, H.: Control of an uncertain fractional order economic system via adaptive sliding mode. Neurocomputing 83, 83–88 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Xin, B., Zhang, J.: Finite-time stabilizing a fractional-order chaotic financial system with market confidence. Nonlinear Dyn. 79(2), 1399–1409 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Zheng, S.: Impulsive stabilization and synchronization of uncertain financial hyperchaotic systems. Kybernetika 52(2), 241–257 (2016)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  12. Tacha, O.I., Volos, C.K., Kyprianidis, I.M., et al.: Analysis, adaptive control and circuit simulation of a novel nonlinear finance system. Appl. Math. Comput. 276(4), 200–217 (2016)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Just, W., Bernard, T., Ostheimer, M., et al.: Mechanism of time-delayed feedback control. Phys. Rev. Lett. 78(2), 203–206 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Chen, G., Yu, X.: On time-delayed feedback control of chaotic systems. IEEE Trans. Circuits Syst. I 46(6), 767–772 (1999)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  15. Chen, L., Chen, G.: Controlling chaos in an economic model. Physica A 374(1), 349–358 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Salarieh, H., Alasty, A.: Delayed feedback control via minimum entropy strategy in an economic model. Physica A 387(4), 851–860 (2008)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  17. Chen, W.-C.: Dynamics and control of a financial system with time-delayed feedbacks. Chaos Solitons Fractals 37(4), 1198–1207 (2008)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  18. Son, W.-S., Park, Y.-J.: Delayed feedback on the dynamical model of a financial system. Chaos Solitons Fractals 44(4–5), 208–217 (2011)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  19. Zhao, M., Wang, J.: \(H_{\infty }\) control of a chaotic finance system in the presence of external disturbance and input time-delay. Appl. Math. Comput. 233(4), 320–327 (2014)

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  20. Amato, F., Cosentino, C., Merola, A.: On the region of attraction of nonlinear quadratic systems. Automatica 43(12), 2119–2123 (2007)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  21. Amato, F., Ambrosino, R., Ariola, M., et al.: State feedback control of nonlinear quadratic systems. In: Proceedings of the 46th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control, New Orleans, 12–14 Dec. 2007. pp. 1699–1703 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  22. Merola, A., Cosentino, C., Colacino, D., Amato, F.: Optimal control of uncertain nonlinear quadratic systems. Automatica 83, 345–350 (2017)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  23. Chen, F., Xu, S., Zou, Y., Zhang, M.: Finite-time boundedness and stabilisation for a class of non-linear quadratic time-delay systems with disturbances. IET Control Theory Appl. 7(13), 1683–1688 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  24. Souza, C.E., de Coutinho, D.: Delay-dependent regional stabilization of nonlinear quadratic time-delay systems. In: Proceedings of the 19th World Congress (IFAC), Cape Town, 24–29 August 2014. pp. 10084–10089 (2014)

    Google Scholar 

  25. Chen, F., Kang, S., Qiao, S., Guo, C.: Exponential stability and stabilization for quadratic discrete-time systems with time delay. Asian J. Control 20(1), 276–285 (2018)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  26. Park, P., Lee, W.I., Lee, S.Y.: Auxiliary function-based integral inequalities for quadratic functions and their applications to time-delay systems. J. Franklin Inst. 352(4), 1378–1396 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  27. Wu, T., Xiong, L., Cao, J., Liu, C.: Further results on robust stability for uncertain neutral systems with distributed delay. J. Inequal. Appl. 2018, 314 (2018)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  28. Chen, Y., Fei, S., Li, Y.: Robust stabilization for uncertain saturated time-delay systems: a distributed-delay-dependent polytopic approach. IEEE Trans. Autom. Control 62(7), 3455–3460 (2017)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  29. Chen, Y., Wang, Z., Fei, S., Han, Q.-L.: Regional stabilization for discrete time-delay systems with actuator saturations via a delay-dependent polytopic approach. IEEE Trans. Autom. Control 64(3), 1257–1264 (2019)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  30. Sun, J., Liu, G.P., Chen, J.: Delay-dependent stability and stabilization of neutral time-delay systems. Int. J. Robust Nonlinear Control 19(1), 1364–1375 (2009)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  31. Chen, Y., Wang, Z., Shen, B., Dong, H.: Exponential synchronization for delayed dynamical networks via intermittent control: dealing with actuator saturations. IEEE Trans. Neural Netw. Learn. Syst. 30(4), 1000–1013 (2019)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  32. Chen, W., Ding, D., Dong, H., Wei, G.: Distributed resilient filtering for power systems subject to denial-of-service attacks. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. Syst. 49(8), 1688–1697 (2019)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Ding, D., Wang, Z., Han, Q.-L.: A set-membership approach to event-triggered filtering for general nonlinear systems over sensor networks. IEEE Trans. Autom. Control (2019). https://doi.org/10.1109/TAC2019.2934389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Seuret, A., Gouaisbaut, F.: Hierarchy of LMI conditions for the stability analysis of time-delay systems. Syst. Control Lett. 81, 1–7 (2015)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  35. Qian, W., Wang, L., Chen, M.Z.Q.: Local consensus of nonlinear multiagent systems with varying delay coupling. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. Syst. 48(12), 2462–2469 (2018)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Qian, W., Gao, Y., Yang, Y.: Global consensus of multiagent systems with internal delays and communication delays. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. Syst. 49(10), 1961–1970 (2019)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the editors and anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments, which improved the quality of the current manuscript.

Availability of data and materials

Not applicable.

Funding

This work was supported in part by the National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grant 61773156.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors contributed equally to this paper. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yonggang Chen.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Xu, E., Zhang, Y. & Chen, Y. Time-delayed local feedback control for a chaotic finance system. J Inequal Appl 2020, 100 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13660-020-02364-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13660-020-02364-2

Keywords