Skip to main content

Jensen's inequality for monetary utility functions

Abstract

In this paper, we prove that Jensen's inequality holds true for all monetary utility functions with respect to certain convex or concave functions by studying the properties of monetary utility functions, convex functions and concave functions.

1 Introduction and preliminaries

1.1 Introduction

Monetary utility functions have recently attracted much attention in the mathematical finance community, see e.g. [14]. According to [2], a monetary utility function U can be identified with a convex risk measure ρ by the formula U(ξ) = - ρ(ξ); convex risk measure, introduced in [5, 6], is a popular notion in particular since the Basel II accord. Some times we want to not only measure the utility of an uncertain random variable but also estimate the utility of its function (see e.g. 2.2). Jensen's inequality will be a useful tool solving this problem.

It is well-known that Jensen's inequality holds true for classical expectation, which, in terms of operator, can be seen as a particular type of monetary utility functions. But with respect to some convex or concave functions, it does not hold true for all monetary utility functions, as stated in our Example 2.1. This suggests a natural question: with respect to which kind of convex or concave functions does it hold true? In this paper, we study this question and give a sufficient and reasonable condition under which Jensen's inequality holds for all monetary utility functions.

1.2 Notations and assumptions

Let ( Ω , F , ) be a probability space. Denote by L the collection of all real-valued essentially bounded -measurable random variables in ( Ω , F , ) . The Definition 1.1 and Remark 1.1 are cited from [2].

Definition 1.1. A function U: L is called a monetary utility function if it is concave, non-decreasing with respect to the order of L , satisfies the normalization condition U(0) = 0 and has the cash-invariance property (U(X + b) = U(X) + b for every X L and b ).

Remark 1.1. The normalization U(0) = 0 does not restrict the generality as it may be obtained by adding a constant to U.

2 Jensen's inequality for monetary utility functions

In this section, we will show our main results and give two examples. For proving the results, we need Proposition 2.1 on monetary utility functions.

Proposition 2.1. LetU: L be a monetary utility function. Then for any k , X L , we have

i U k X k U X , if  0 k 1 ;
(2.1)
ii U k X k U X , if  k 0 or k 1 .
(2.2)

Proof.

(i) If 0 ≤ k ≤ 1, for the concavity of U, we have

U ( k X + ( 1 - k ) Y ) kU ( X ) + ( 1 - k ) U ( Y ) .

Take Y = 0 and consider U(0) = 0, then we have

U ( k X ) kU ( X ) + ( 1 - k ) U ( 0 ) =kU ( X ) .

(ii) If k ≥ 1, then 0< 1 k 1. By (2.1) we have

U 1 k k X 1 k U ( k X ) .

It follows that

U ( k X ) kU ( X ) .
(2.3)

If -1 ≤ k ≤ 0, then 0 ≤ -k ≤ 1. By (2.1) we have

U ( ( - k ) X ) ( - k ) U ( X ) .

Since

0=U ( 0 ) =U 1 2 k X + 1 2 ( - k X ) 1 2 U ( k X ) + 1 2 U ( - k X ) ,

therefore

U ( - k X ) - U ( k X ) ,
(2.4)
- k U ( X ) U ( - k X ) - U ( k X ) .

Hence

U ( k X ) kU ( X ) .

If k ≤ -1, then -k ≥ 1. By (2.3) we have

U ( k X ) =U ( ( - k ) ( - X ) ) ( - k ) U ( - X ) .

Combining the above inequality with (2.4) which is actually true for all k in R, we have

U ( k X ) ( - k ) U ( - X ) ( - k ) ( - U ( X ) ) =kU ( X ) .

The proof of Proposition 2.1 is complete.

   □

Now let us introduce the main results of this paper, i.e. Jensen's inequality for monetary utility functions.

Theorem 2.1. Let φ be a convex function on . Suppose that for anyx, φ + ( x ) 0and φ - ( x ) 1 . Then for anyX L and any monetary utility functionU: L , we have φ(U(X)) ≤ U(φ(X)).

Proof. As stated in Definition 1.1, for every X L , U(X) is finite, i.e. U ( X ) , so we have

φ + ( U ( X ) ) 0 and φ - ( U ( X ) ) 1.

For any

α [ φ - ( U ( X ) ) , φ + ( U ( X ) ) ] [ 0 , 1 ] ,

based on the subgradient inequality in [7], we have

φ ( x ) α ( x - U ( X ) ) +φ ( U ( X ) ) ,x.

For the arbitrariness of x, we have

φ ( X ) α ( X - U ( X ) ) +φ ( U ( X ) ) .

Consider the monotonicity and cash-invariance property of U and (2.1) in Proposition 2.1, then we have

U ( φ ( X ) ) U ( α ( X - U ( X ) ) + φ ( U ( X ) ) ) = U ( α X ) - α U ( X ) + φ ( U ( X ) ) α U ( X ) - α U ( X ) + φ ( U ( X ) ) .

Hence

φ ( U ( X ) ) U ( φ ( X ) ) .

   □

It is also possible to obtain the Jensen inequality for monetary utility functions with respect to certain concave functions (Theorem 2.2) and prove it by the subgradient inequality in [7] and (2.2) in Proposition 2.1. As the proof is very similar with the proof of Theorem 2.1, we omit it and just give the result.

Theorem 2.2. Let ψ be a concave function on . Suppose that for anyx, ψ + ( x ) 0or ψ - ( x ) 1. Then for anyX L and any monetary utility functionU: L , we have ψ(U(X)) ≥ U(ψ(X)).

Then let us illustrate the reasonableness of the conditions on convex and concave functions in Theorems 2.1 and 2.2 through an example. Actually, Jensen's inequality usually is not true for all monetary utility functions even when the related convex or concave function is a linear function.

Example 2.1. Let φ(x) = kx + a (k < 0 or k > 1) and ψ(x) = hx + b (0 < h < 1), obviously φ (respectively ψ) is a convex (respectively concave) function on that do not satisfy the condition in Theorem 2.1 (respectively Theorem 2.2). We consider a particular type of monetary utility function U, the entropic utility function in [4], which is defined as

U ( X ) :=- ln E [ exp ( - X ) ] .
(2.5)

We choose a X L such that { X = 0 } = { X = 1 } =0.5. It is easy to check that U(kX) < kU(X) and U(hX) > hU(X). Then we have

φ ( U ( X ) ) = k U ( X ) + a > U ( k X ) + a = U ( k X + a ) = U ( φ ( X ) ) , ψ ( U ( X ) ) = h U ( X ) + b < U ( h X ) + b = U ( h X + b ) = U ( ψ ( X ) ) .

Thus Jensen's inequality does not holds. So the conditions in Theorems 2.1 and 2.2 are reasonable.

At the end of this paper, let us discuss an application of Jensen's inequality for monetary utility functions.

Example 2.2. We still consider the entropic utility function. Sometimes, we want to estimate the entropic utility of X+ or -X- using the entropic utility of the future outcome X. For this kind of problem, Jensen's inequality will be a useful tool. Let φ(x) = x+, ψ(x) = -x-, then φ is a convex function satisfying the condition in Theorem 2.1 and ψ is a concave function satisfying the condition in Theorem 2.2 By Theorems 2.1 and 2.2 we have

- ln E [ exp ( - X + ) ] ( - ln E [ exp ( - X ) ] ) + , - ln E [ exp ( - ( - X - ) ) ] - ( - ln E [ exp ( - X ) ] ) - .

References

  1. Delbaen F, Peng S, Rosazza Gianin E: Representation of the penalty term of dynamic concave utilities. Finance and Stochastics 2010, 14(3):449–472. 10.1007/s00780-009-0119-7

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Jouini E, Schachermayer W, Touzi N: Optimal risk sharing for law invariant monetary utility functions. Mathematical Finance 2008, 18(2):269–292. 10.1111/j.1467-9965.2007.00332.x

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Filipović D, Kupper M: Equilibrium Prices for Monetary Utility Functions. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance(IJTAF) 2008, 11(3):325–343. 10.1142/S0219024908004828

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Acciaio B: Optimal risk sharing with non-monotone monetary functionals. Finance and Stochastics 2007, 11: 267–289. 10.1007/s00780-007-0036-6

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Föllmer H, Schied A: Convex measures of risk and trading constraints. Finance and Stochastics 2002, 6(4):429–447. 10.1007/s007800200072

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Frittelli M, Rosazza Gianin E: Putting order in risk measures. Journal of Banking & Finance 2002, 26(7):1473–1486. [http://www.geocities.ws/smhurtado/RiskMeasures.pdf]

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Rockafellar RT: Convex Analysis. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1970.

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the referees for their detailed comments and valuable suggestions. This research was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 10971220), the FANEDD (No. 200919), and the National Undergraduate Innovation Experiment Project of China (No. 091029030).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jing Liu.

Additional information

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Authors' contributions

JL study the properties of the functions, carried out the proof of the results and drafted the manuscript. LJ conceived of the study, designed the research method, and helped to draft the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 2.0 International License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/2.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Liu, J., Jiang, L. Jensen's inequality for monetary utility functions. J Inequal Appl 2012, 128 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1186/1029-242X-2012-128

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/1029-242X-2012-128

Keywords